Publication
Article
The American Journal of Managed Care
Author(s):
Vaccination of children born in the United States in 2009 will save 1.2 million quality-adjusted life-years, generating $184 billion in social value net of vaccination costs.
ABSTRACT
Objectives: To determine the lifetime social value of using the guideline-recommended vaccines for children born in the United States in 2009.
Study Design: This study utilized an economic model with parameter values sourced from clinical and observational data, as well as the literature.
Methods: The model quantified the health effects of routine vaccination for 14 diseases in terms of quality-adjusted life-years (QALYs) saved. The health effects were then valued by applying an economic value of a QALY. Producers’ profits were estimated using data on vaccine prices, profit margins, and the number of vaccines administrated in the 2009 US birth cohort. The costs of producing the vaccines were subtracted from the value of the health effects to yield the total social value of vaccination. The producers’ and consumers’ shares of this social value were calculated. Sensitivity analyses were conducted to determine how results depend on underlying parameter assumptions.
Results: Estimates indicated that vaccination of this cohort will save 1.2 million QALYs, relative to no vaccination. Of those health gains, 88% stemmed from reduced mortality and 12% from reduced morbidity. We estimated a social value of $184.1 billion from these gains, of which $3.4 billion accrues to manufacturers as profits, while $180.7 billion accrues to the rest of society. In sensitivity analysis, the total social value ranged from $40 billion to $675 billion, and the manufacturers’ share ranged from 0.3% to 11.5%.
Conclusions: Policy makers should account for this social value when considering policies affecting incentives to vaccinate and develop new vaccines.
Am J Manag Care. 2017;23(1):41-47
Take-Away Points
The innovation of childhood vaccines has resulted in a decline in infectious disease, as well as gains in length and quality of life. Smallpox has been eradicated, poliomyelitis is nearly eliminated, and many other vaccine-preventable diseases have seen declines in incidence.1-3 Although adverse events (AEs) can occur with vaccines,4-7 and recent research has focused on their rising costs,8-10 the postvaccine era has seen life expectancy increase 15 to 25 years compared with the pre-vaccine era, and further gains are expected.3,11 Evidence suggests a large share of these survival gains is due to the control of infectious disease through vaccination.3
When encouraged by public health policies, vaccination also provides a benefit to government and private payers by reducing overall costs and increasing population health. The CDC has cited evidence that common childhood vaccinations save over $5 in direct medical costs and effects on productivity for every $1 spent.12 Maciosek and colleagues found that preventative childhood immunization produced annual net medical savings of $267 per person.13 Vaccination also generates community (herd) immunity by reducing disease incidence and transmission, thus resulting in a healthier population.14
Because vaccines have been successful at preventing disease, the public is no longer regularly confronted with many vaccine-preventable diseases, and the health and economic benefits of vaccination may be underappreciated.15 As childhood vaccines have reduced disease prevalence, real and perceived AEs of vaccination have become more salient to parents than the vaccine-targeted diseases.16,17 Consequently, vaccination rates in many US states have declined in recent years.17 As vaccination rates slip, the risk of new outbreaks increases.18
Moreover, although consumers are insulated from the cost of many vaccines, vaccine cost is an important consideration for payers and providers and has been criticized.19 This focus on AEs and costs has obscured vaccines’ overall value to individuals and society. Previous research has yet to show how the total social value of vaccines is divided between innovators who develop these technologies and patients and the broader society who benefit from them. Therefore, in this study, we sought to measure the social value of childhood vaccines in the United States and the distribution of that value to manufacturers versus the rest of society.
The concept of social value of therapies and its distribution between manufacturers and patients has been described in other disease areas. For instance, Grabrowski et al found that statin usage resulted in a social value of $1.25 trillion, of which patients received 76%.20 Yin et al performed a similar analysis on tyrosine kinase inhibitors for the treatment of chronic myeloid leukemia and found a social value of $143 billion—90% of which was retained by patients.21 Recent gains in cancer survival have provided $1.9 trillion of additional social value, with 81% to 95% of that being retained by patients.22 Lastly, HIV/AIDS therapies have generated $1.38 trillion in social value, with 95% accruing to patients.23 Such analyses are net monetary benefit analyses, which is a common economic way of thinking about value which is distinct from cost-effectiveness analysis. The aim is to measure the total value a given health intervention generates for society, and how that value is distributed across patients and manufacturers.
This study applied similar methods to determine the social value of childhood vaccines for a birth cohort in the United States. Consistent with previous research, social value was defined from an economic perspective as the quantity of resources, in monetary terms, that society would be willing to give up in order to retain the health gains attributable to vaccines. Put another way, the overall social value of vaccines equals the aggregate value retained by consumers (above the actual payments for vaccines) plus the value retained by manufacturers (in the form of vaccine profits). We decomposed the social value into the shares accruing to manufacturers versus the rest of society. For infectious diseases, the social value includes not only those vaccinated, but also those not vaccinated who benefit from the reduction in disease incidence.15
METHODSOverview
The study entailed constructing an economic model based on observational and clinical data. The model calculates the social value of the routine pediatric vaccination schedule used in the United States in 2009. We do so by quantifying the health effects of routine vaccination of children born in the United States in 2009. In particular, vaccines to prevent the following 14 diseases were considered: congenital rubella syndrome, diphtheria, haemophilus influenzae type b (Hib), hepatitis A, hepatitis B, measles, mumps, pertussis, pneumococcus-related diseases (including pneumococcal disease, otitis media, pneumonia, and meningitis), polio, rotavirus, rubella, tetanus, and varicella. The influenza vaccine was not included because its changing seasonal nature would have required different methods.
The social value was estimated by applying an economic value to the health effects of vaccines, measured in terms of quality-adjusted life-years (QALYs) saved through vaccination. QALYs take into account both duration and quality of life. A year in perfect health would be measured as 1 QALY, whereas death counts as 0. From the value of the QALYs gained, the costs to produce vaccines were subtracted. This yielded the social value—or in economic terms, the total surplus—of vaccines, and represents the economic value of the health gains from vaccines minus the resources society spent to produce them. The shares of the total surplus accruing to manufacturers (producer surplus) versus the rest of society (consumer surplus) were also calculated.
It should be noted that vaccine-preventable illnesses impose additional costs on society beyond the utility loss infected individuals experience, including caregiver utility loss and the use of special services for persistent disability. Therefore our estimate of the health value of vaccination should be considered a lower bound.
In addition, one should exercise caution in interpreting the results of this framework for rotavirus, since in industrialized countries like the United States, the costs of rotavirus are mainly hospitalization and caregiver utility loss, as rotavirus mortality and morbidity are lower in the industrialized setting. In contrast, many of the other studied vaccines target illnesses that imposed a high mortality and morbidity burden in the pre-vaccine era.24
Data Sources
According to the CDC, 4,130,665 children were born in the United States in 2009.25 The health effects of vaccination in this cohort were estimated by combining data from the literature with life tables from the Human Mortality Database.26 From the literature, we obtained for each disease data on cases of illness prevented, premature deaths avoided, average age of onset, average age at death from the disease, average duration of disease, and utility loss. Specific parameter values and sources are available in the eAppendix (eAppendices available at www.ajmc.com). The survival benefits of vaccination were net of adverse reactions to vaccination. To obtain the economic value of a QALY, we considered values generated by revealed and stated preference studies.27,28 A mid-range value of $150,000 was used and varied in sensitivity analysis.
Estimating manufacturers’ profits required 3 types of data: 1) data on vaccine prices, 2) data on manufacturers’ profit margins, and 3) data on the number of vaccines administered in the 2009 US birth cohort. We obtained data on prices (available in the eAppendix) from the CDC Vaccines for Children Program website, which contains archived data on public and private vaccine prices from 2008 to 2015.29
We obtained data on vaccine manufacturers’ profit margins from annual reports and financial statements. When measuring manufacturers’ profits, we used the gross profit margin, which represents the sales volume minus production costs. Obtaining a companywide average across the top 5 vaccine manufacturers produced an average gross profit of 75%.30-34 This is a conservative approach, as gross profits do not subtract out manufacturer research and development (R&D) and marketing expenses. By using the gross profit margin, we can view vaccines’ social value as society’s benefit from vaccination, and society’s investment in R&D as the cost of inventing and developing the vaccines. (Subtracting R&D from profits would negate this framing.) This framing is useful because investments should be undertaken when the benefits (ie, the return on investment) exceeds the cost; social value is an important part of this equation. Moreover, R&D costs include the costs of many failures that the innovator encountered on the way to the given successful product; there is not an established method for measuring R&D costs for vaccines.
To estimate the number of vaccines administered, we required data on vaccine coverage rates, dosage schedules, wastage, and the cohort size. Following previous work, we assumed that 53% of vaccine doses were publicly (vs privately) administered and the wastage rate—the rate at which additional vaccines must be purchased beyond those needed for each vaccinated child because some vaccines will be unused—was 5%.35 We obtained vaccination rates,36 the recommended vaccination schedule,37 and the size of the cohort25 from the CDC. Doses administered between ages 0 and 18 were included, but the costs of any adult booster doses were excluded. Given that any adult booster doses occur many years into the child’s life, whereas the lives saved and illnesses avoided from vaccination are realized mainly in early childhood, the effect of the focus on childhood doses should be minimal.
Analysis
The 3 analytic steps are described broadly below. Additional detail is provided in the eAppendix. Throughout the analysis, monetary values were inflation-adjusted to 2014 US dollars using the Consumer Price Index,38 and an annual discount rate of 3% was applied.
Step 1: Value Health Effects of Vaccination
The health effects of vaccines were calculated by summing the changes in morbidity and mortality among the 2009 US birth cohort due to vaccination. The mortality effects were calculated as the number of deaths averted from vaccination multiplied by the QALYs the typical child would lose from dying of the given disease (calculated as average life expectancy minus average age at death from the given disease times aged-adjusted utility). The morbidity effects were calculated as the number of cases of illness prevented through vaccination times the typical duration of illness times the disutility from the given illness. The health effects of vaccines in QALYs were then converted to economic terms by valuing each QALY at $150,000.39-41 This yielded the economic value of the health effects of vaccination.
Step 2: Estimate Manufacturers’ Profits
Vaccine manufacturers’ profits from a given vaccine were estimated by multiplying the vaccine’s price by the number of vaccines sold by the profit margin. Although vaccines typically consist of multiple doses, and vaccination rates vary by dose, in the profit calculations we assumed that all children who received the first dose of a vaccine would also receive all subsequent doses. This assumption overestimates profits because some children will not receive all doses, and manufacturers’ profits will be lower than they would be had these children received all of their doses.
Step 3: Calculate Total Value
Using the results of the previous 2 steps, we calculated consumer, producer, and total surplus (ie, social value). Consumer surplus was calculated as the value of the health effects of vaccines (from Step 1) minus the cost of the vaccines (from Step 2). Producer surplus equaled the manufacturer profits (from Step 2). Consumer and producer surplus together yielded the total surplus.
Sensitivity Analyses
±
±
We performed analyses to test the sensitivity of the model to the parameters. Specifically, we varied all parameters by 10%, except for the disease-specific vaccination rates, which were varied by 5% to avoid specifying rates over 100%. In addition, we also varied the value of a QALY from $50,000 through $250,000 to reflect the wide range of values in the literature, and varied the discount rate from 0% to 6%. Lastly, we conducted an analysis, which included the parents’ time cost to take the children to receive the vaccines, taking into account that multiple vaccines may be given in the same visit.
RESULTS
The health effects of vaccination are reported in Table 1. Compared with no vaccination, an estimated 1.2 million QALYs will be saved due to vaccination among children born in the United States in 2009, for a value of $185.2 billion. Because vaccines typically prevent deaths that would have occurred in childhood, these avoided deaths save a large number of QALYs, whereas QALY gains from avoided illness are more modest. Consequently, 88% of the health value of vaccines is due to avoided death compared with 12% due to avoided illness. Among vaccines, diphtheria, tetanus, and pertussis (DTaP/Tdap) will have the largest health value by an order of magnitude, at nearly 800,000 QALYs saved for a value of $119 billion. Other vaccines with large health values are pneumococcus-related diseases (154,000 QALYs, $23 billion); measles, mumps, and rubella (MMR) (135,000 QALYs, $19 billion); and hepatitis B (79,000 QALYs, $12 billion). The smallest health value will be for rotavirus, at 5264 QALYs and $790 million.
Table 2 reports estimates of manufacturers’ revenues, costs, gross and net profits by vaccines given to the 2009 US birth cohort. Estimated profits are the lowest for the hepatitis A vaccine ($109 million gross, $36 million net), and the highest for pneumococcus-related diseases ($1.0 billion gross, $350 million net). Across all 14 diseases, vaccines generate an estimated $4.5 billion in revenues, $1.1 billion in costs, $3.4 billion in gross profits, and $1.1 billion in net profits.
The total social value by vaccine and its distribution across manufacturers and consumers are reported in Table 3. Consumers’ share of value, or surplus, ranges from $10 million for rotavirus to $119 billion for DTaP/Tdap. Vaccines producing the greatest consumer surplus do not necessarily provide the largest profit, or producer surplus, to manufacturers. Total social value ranges from $595 million from rotavirus to $119 billion from DTaP/Tdap, with the full vaccination schedule generating $184 billion in social value (Figure 1), or $45,000 per child. Of that total social value, 1.8% accrues to manufacturers, whereas 98.2% accrues to the rest of society. The manufacturers’ share ranges from 0.3% for DTaP/Tdap to 98.3% for rotavirus, and is less than 15% for 7 out of the 9 vaccines.
±
In sensitivity analyses, we found that the model is most sensitive to the economic value of a QALY, the premature deaths prevented from vaccination, and the discount rate, which together contributed 98.1% of the variance in results (Figure 2). In simulations, the total social value ranged from $153 billion to $227 billion, and the manufacturers’ share ranged from 1.3% to 2.6%. In other words, varying parameters by 10% maintained a social value of at least $37,172 per child, with at least 97% of the value retained as consumer surplus. In addition, varying the value of a QALY from $50,000 to $250,000 led to social value ranging from $61 billion to $308 billion, and varying the discount rate from 0% to 6% led to social value ranging from $447 billion to $107 billion. Subtracting parents’ time cost led to a social value of $182 billion and manufacture share of 1.8%.
DISCUSSION
Our estimates suggest that routine childhood vaccination produces a large social value. In particular, we found that vaccination will save 1.2 million QALYs among children born in the United States in 2009, relative to a counterfactual of no vaccination. Vaccines treating common diseases, such as DTaP/Tdap, pneumococcus, and MMR, generate a particularly large share of the health benefits.
Childhood illness is often transitory, but many childhood diseases have nontrivial fatality rates, and a death in childhood costs many years of healthy life. Therefore, it is not surprising that the bulk of these health gains (88%) stems from reduced mortality, with the remainder (12%) from reduced morbidity. Valuing each life-year at $150,000 and subtracting the production costs of vaccines, we found that vaccination of the 2009 birth cohort generated $184 billion in social value, or $45,000 per child. Of this, $3.4 billion (2%) accrues to manufacturers in the form of profits, while $180.7 billion (98%) is retained by the rest of society. Sensitivity analysis showed that the large social value and large share retained by society are robust to a wide range of plausible parameters.
The 2% manufacturers’ share of social value we found is smaller than that found in similar analyses of other health interventions. The manufacturers’ share of social value was between 5% to 24% in HIV/AIDS, chronic myeloid leukemia, and heart disease.20,21,23 The distribution of gains between manufacturers and the rest of society is determined by the cost of the intervention and the health gains it produces. Health gains will generally be larger in the context of diseases that are prevalent or take life early. Therefore, it is not surprising that childhood vaccines come out favorably in these comparisons, as they are among the most cost-effective health interventions42 and they preserve the health of children, who, in the absence of a devastating childhood illness, typically go on to lead a long, healthy life. To put the health results in context, in other industries, the producers’ share of total social value has ranged from 4% for minivans43 to 24% for broadband Internet.44
The fact that 98% of the social value from existing childhood vaccines goes to children and their families is good news for access to current vaccines; however, it has longer-term implications for innovation. A 2% share of value suggests relatively weak incentives for the development of new and improved vaccines, relative to the incentives to develop cancer drugs, cholesterol-lowering drugs, or broadband Internet. However, there is debate in the literature about the exact manufacturer share of surplus required to optimally incentivize innovation, and therefore, although this study informs the debate, it does not determine optimal vaccine pricing.45,46
Limitations
Because the model relies on inputs from the literature, it is limited by their availability and quality. When exact parameters were not available, conservative assumptions were made. For example, costs and profits were overestimated by assuming children who receive 1 dose of a vaccine receive all subsequent doses, thus underestimating social value and overestimating manufacturers’ share. In cases in which illness is usually short and mild but can be severe and long-lasting (eg, polio), we assumed a short and mild case in our utility calculations. In calculating profit margins, we assumed the companywide profit margin applied to a given vaccine, although vaccines may comprise a less profitable division of pharmaceutical firms.47 We also used gross margin, which does not take R&D and marketing costs into account, rather than net margin, so that we could consider the social value as the return on society’s investment in developing the vaccine.
Additionally, while the 2009 birth cohort was selected for this analysis due to the availability of data on the health effects of vaccination,24 it has the drawback of including in the analysis a year of shortage of the Hib vaccine.48 However, given the scale of the findings of this study, this consideration likely had minimal impact.
We present results at the aggregate and vaccine levels, although comparison across vaccines is imperfect. In general, prices will be higher at launch and lower after entry by competitors; however, for the childhood vaccination schedule as a whole, these lifecycle factors will tend to balance out, with little effect on our aggregate estimates.
Typical valuations of vaccines, including cost-effectiveness analyses, only partially capture their full social value,49,50 and this study, too, is not comprehensive. For example, this paper does not consider caregiver utility or the costs of persistent disabilities due to vaccine-preventable illnesses. In addition, it does not explicitly consider herd immunity. Herd immunity is simultaneously a large source of social value as it prevents the spread of costly illnesses for payers and society, but it is also a likely reason that some parents eschew vaccination. These dynamics should be further explored in future research.
Beyond benefiting society as a whole, public policies encouraging vaccination have value for payers in particular. Without a vaccination requirement, there is diminished incentive to vaccinate beneficiaries. There is frequent turnover in health plans and vaccinated members may leave a plan within a few years, whereas new members may come from plans with lower vaccination rates. With strong vaccination policies, even if plans lose members the plan has vaccinated, they are likely to gain members that are also vaccinated, so the risk due to turnover is reduced.
CONCLUSIONS
The childhood vaccination schedule has large benefits on population health, saving an estimated 1.2 million QALYs, and generating over $184 billion in social value, or $45,000 per child. The high social value is corroborated by the CDC37 and the American Academy of Pediatrics, both of which recommend routine childhood vaccination.51 Of this social value, $3.4 billion (2%) accrues to manufacturers, while 180.7 billion (98%) is retained by the rest of society. While a small manufacturers’ share may facilitate access to vaccines in the short term, it also has implications for the incentive to develop new and improved vaccines to provide further health gains in the future.
Author Affiliations: University of Chicago (TJP), Chicago, IL; Precision Health Economics (JTS, SG, TTS, YW), Los Angeles, CA; Sanofi Pasteur (AC, PH), Swiftwater, PA; Leslie Dan Faculty of Pharmacy, University of Toronto (AC), Ontario, Canada; University of California, San Francisco (WMA), San Francisco, CA
Source of Funding: Financial support for this research was provided Sanofi-Pasteur.
Author Disclosures: Dr Philipson was hired by Sanofi Pasteur to consult on this manuscript. Drs Snider and Wu, Ms Green, and Mr. Schwartz are employed by Precision Health Economics (PHE), which receives consulting fees from life sciences companies and received funding from Sanofi Pasteur to conduct this research. Dr Chit and M. Hosbach are employed by Sanofi Pasteur, a major vaccine manufacturer. Dr Aubry was hired by PHE to consult on this manuscript.
Authorship Information: Concept and design (TJP, JTS, AC, PH, YW, WMA); acquisition of data (TJP, JTS, AC, SG, TTS); analysis and interpretation of data (TJP, JTS, AC, YW, WMA); drafting of the manuscript (TJP, JTS, PH, TTS, YW); critical revision of the manuscript for important intellectual content (TJP, JTS, AC, TTS, YW, WMA); statistical analysis (TJP, JTS, AC, YW); provision of patients or study materials (TJP); obtaining funding (TJP, AC, PH); administrative, technical, or logistic support (TJP, SG, TTS); scientific programming (SG); and supervision (TJP, AC).
Address Correspondence to: Julia Thornton Snider, PhD, Precision Health Economics, 11100 Santa Monica Blvd, Ste 500, Los Angeles, CA 90025. E-mail: Julia.Snider@precisionhealtheconomics.com.
REFERENCES
1. Stéphenne J. Vaccines as a global imperative—a business perspective. Health Aff (Millwood). 2011;30(6):1042-1048. doi: 10.1377/hlthaff.2011.0338.
2. Rappuoli R, Miller HI, Falkow S. The intangible value of vaccination. Science. 2002;297(5583):937-939.
3. Rappuoli R, Mandl CW, Black S, De Gregorio E. Vaccines for the twenty-first century society. Nat Rev Immunol. 2011;11(12):865-872. doi: 10.1038/nri3085.
4. Jefferson T, Rudin M, Di Pietrantonj C. Adverse events after immunisation with aluminium-containing DTP vaccines: systematic review of the evidence. Lancet Infect Dis. 2004;4(2):84-90.
5. Geier DA, Geier MR. A case-control study of serious autoimmune adverse events following hepatitis B immunization. Autoimmunity. 2005;38(4):295-301.
6. Howson CP, Fineberg HV. Adverse events following pertussis and rubella vaccines: summary of a report of the Institute of Medicine. JAMA. 1992;267(3):392-396.
7. Stratton KR, Howe CJ, Johnston RB Jr. Adverse events associated with childhood vaccines other than pertussis and rubella: summary of a report from the Institute of Medicine. JAMA. 1994;271(20):1602-1605.
8. Lindley MC, Shen AK, Orenstein WA, Rodewald LE, Birkhead GS. Financing the delivery of vaccines to children and adolescents: challenges to the current system. Pediatrics. 2009;124(suppl 5):S548-S557. doi: 10.1542/peds.2009-1542O.
9. Davis MM, Zimmerman JL, Wheeler JR, Freed GL. Childhood vaccine purchase costs in the public sector: past trends, future expectations. Am J Public Health. 2002;92(12):1982-1987.
10. Scheifele DW. New vaccines and the rising costs of caring. Paediatr Child Health. 2000;5(7):371-372.
11. Oeppen J, Vaupel JW. Broken limits to life expectancy. Science. 2002;296(5570):1029-1031.
12. HHS. An ounce of prevention...what are the returns? CDC website. http://www.cdc.gov/mmwr/pdf/other/ozprev.pdf. Published October 1999. Accessed November 22, 2016.
13. Maciosek MV, Coffield AB, Flottemesch TJ, Edwards NM, Solberg LI. Greater use of preventive services in U.S. health care could save lives at little or no cost. Health Aff (Millwood). 2010;29(9):1656-1660. doi: 10.1377/hlthaff.2008.0701.
14. Brisson M, Edmunds WJ. Economic evaluation of vaccination programs: the impact of herd-immunity. Med Decis Making. 2003;23(1):76-82.
15. Philipson T. Economic epidemiology and infectious diseases. Handbook of Health Economics. 2000;1:1761-1799.
16. Goldstein KP, Philipson TJ, Joo H, Daum RS. The effect of epidemic measles on immunization rates. JAMA. 1996;276(1):56-58.
17. Seither R, Masalovich S, Knighton CL, Mellerson J, Singleton JA, Greby SM; CDC. Vaccination coverage among children in kindergarten—United States, 2013-14 school year. MMWR Morb Mortal Wkly Rep. 2014;63(41):913-920.
18. Gangarosa EJ, Galazka AM, Wolfe CR, et al. Impact of anti-vaccine movements on pertussis control: the untold story. Lancet. 1998;351(9099):356-361.
19. Rosenthal E. The price of prevention: vaccine costs are soaring. The New York Times website. http://www.nytimes.com/2014/07/03/health/Vaccine-Costs-Soaring-Paying-Till-It-Hurts.html?_r=0. Published July 2, 2014. Accessed August 11, 2015.
20. Grabowski DC, Lakdawalla DN, Goldman DP, et al. The large social value resulting from use of statins warrants steps to improve adherence and broaden treatment. Health Aff (Millwood). 2012;31(10):2276-2285. doi: 10.1377/hlthaff.2011.1120.
21. Yin W, Penrod JR, Maclean R, Lakdawalla DN, Philipson T. Value of survival gains in chronic myeloid leukemia. Am J Manag Care. 2012;18(suppl 11):S257-S264.
22. Lakdawalla DN, Sun EC, Jena AB, Reyes CM, Goldman DP, Philipson TJ. An economic evaluation of the war on cancer. J Health Econ. 2010;29(3):333-346. doi: 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2010.02.006.
23. Philipson TJ, Jena AB. Who benefits from new medical technologies? estimates of consumer and producer surpluses for HIV/AIDS drugs. Forum Health Econ Policy. 2006;9(2):a3.
24. Zhou F, Ortega-Sanchez IR, Guris D, Shefer A, Lieu T, Seward JF. An economic analysis of the universal varicella vaccination program in the United States. J Infect Dis. 2008;197(suppl 2):S156-S164. doi: 10.1086/522135.
25. Martin JA, Hamilton BE, Ventura SJ, et al. Births: final data for 2009. Natl Vital Stat Rep. 2011;60(1):1-70.
26. USA complete data series. Human Mortality Database website. http://www.mortality.org/cgi-bin/hmd/country.php?cntr=USA&level=1. Accessed July 10, 2015.
27. Viscusi WK, Aldy JE. The value of a statistical life: a critical review of market estimates throughout the world. J Risk Uncertainty. 2003;27(1):5-76.
28. Hirth RA, Chernew ME, Miller E, Fendrick AM, Weissert WG. Willingness to pay for a quality-adjusted life year: in search of a standard. Med Decis Making. 2000;20(3):332-342.
29. Vaccines for Children Program: archived CDC vaccine price list as of December 1, 2009. CDC website. http://www.cdc.gov/vaccines/programs/vfc/awardees/vaccine-management/price-list/2009/2009-12-01.html#pediatric. Published December 1, 2009. Accessed July 10, 2015.
30. GSK is changing: annual report 2009. GlaxoSmithKline website. http://www.gsk.com/media/279942/annual-report-2009.pdf. Published 2009. Accessed July 10, 2015.
31. Pfizer Inc 2009 financial report. Pfizer website. https://www.pfizer.com/files/annualreport/2009/financial/financial2009.pdf. Accessed July 10, 2015.
32. Form 10-K [Merck & Co Inc, annual report for the fiscal year ended December 31, 2009]. http://s21.q4cdn.com/755037021/files/doc_financials/annualReports/2009/Form-10-K-2009-final.pdf. Accessed July 10, 2015.
33. Form 20-F [Novartis annual report for the fiscal year ended December 31, 2009]. Novartis website. https://www.novartis.com/sites/www.novartis.com/files/Novartis-20-F-2009.pdf. Accessed July 10, 2015.
34. Gambhir D, Lawrence A, Aggarwal A, Misra R, Mandal SK, Naik S. Association of tumor necrosis factor alpha and IL-10 promoter polymorphisms with rheumatoid arthritis in North Indian population. Rheumatol Int. 2010;30(9):1211-1217. doi: 10.1007/s00296-009-1131-0.
35. Zhou F, Shefer A, Wenger J, et al. Economic evaluation of the routine childhood immunization program in the United States, 2009. Pediatrics. 2014;133(4):577-585. doi: 10.1542/peds.2013-0698.
36. National, state, and local area vaccination coverage among children aged 19-35 months—United States, 2011. CDC website. https://www.cdc.gov/mmwr/preview/mmwrhtml/mm6135a1.htm. Published September 7, 2012. Accessed July 10, 2015.
37. CDC. Recommended immunization schedules for persons aged 0 through 18 years—United States, 2009. MMWR Morb Mortal Wkly Rep. 2009;57(51&52);Q-1-Q-4.
38. Consumer Price Index. Bureau of Labor Statistics website. http://data.bls.gov/cgi-bin/surveymost. Accessed July 10, 2015.
39. Weinstein MC, Siegel JE, Gold MR, Kamlet MS, Russell LB. Recommendations of the Panel on Cost-effectiveness in Health and Medicine. JAMA. 1996;276(15):1253-1258.
40. Gold MR, Stevenson D, Fryback DG. HALYS and QALYS and DALYS, oh my: similarities and differences in summary measures of population health. Ann Rev Public Health. 2002;23:115-134.
41. Russell LB, Gold MR, Siegel JE, Daniels N, Weinstein MC. The role of cost-effectiveness analysis in health and medicine. JAMA. 1996;276(14):1172-1177.
42. Expert panel findings. Copenhagen Consensus Center website. http://www.copenhagenconsensus.com/sites/default/files/outcome_document_updated_1105.pdf. Published 2012. Accessed November 22, 2016.
43. Petrin A. Quantifying the benefits of new products: the case of the minivan. J Polit Econ. 2002;110(4):705-729.
44. Goolsbee A. The value of broadband and the deadweight loss of taxing new technology. The BE Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy. 2006;5(1):1-31.
45. Loury GC. Market structure and innovation. Q J Econ. 1979;93(3):395-410.
46. Nordhaus W. An economic theory of technological change. American Economic Review. 1969;59(2):18-28.
47. Hwang TJ, Kesselheim AS. Vaccine pipeline has grown during the past two decades with more early-stage trials from small and medium-size companies. Health Aff (Millwood). 2016;35(2):219-226. doi: 10.1377/hlthaff.2015.1073.
48. CDC. Continued shortage of Haemophilus influenzae type b (Hib) conjugate vaccines and potential implications for Hib surveillance—United States, 2008. MMWR Morb Mortal Wkly Rep. 2008;57(46):1252.
49. Schwartz JL, Mahmoud A. When not all that counts can be counted: economic evaluations and the value of vaccination. Health Aff (Millwood). 2016;35(2):208-211. doi: 10.1377/hlthaff.2015.1438.
50. Luyten J, Beutels P. The social value of vaccination programs: beyond cost-effectiveness. Health Aff (Millwood). 2016;35(2):212-218. doi: 10.1377/hlthaff.2015.1088.
51. Recommended immunization schedules for persons aged 0 through 18 years, United States, 2015. CDC website. http://www.cdc.gov/vaccines/schedules/downloads/past/2015-child.pdf. Accessed July 10, 2015.
Pervasiveness and Clinical Staff Perceptions of HPV Vaccination Feedback
Pervasiveness and Clinical Staff Perceptions of HPV Vaccination Feedback
2 Commerce Drive
Suite 100
Cranbury, NJ 08512
© 2024 MJH Life Sciences® and AJMC®.
All rights reserved.